Why do some people initiate or prolong conflict when the odds are decidedly against them? We know that the cost-benefit calculations typically underpinning most political decisions do not apply here, or if they do, only in significantly modified form. Rationality as the maximization of preferred outcomes through means-ends calculations governs many of our political choices. Voting behavior typically, but not always, is one such example. But civil war protraction and increased violence may be another matter. Although social network analysis (Parkinson 2013) and game theoretic calculations (e.g., Garfinkel and Skaperdas 2000; Bester and Konrad 2004) can help supply a rational choice approach to civil war protraction, long ago Clausewitz ([1832] 1984 p.138) warned that:
Modern wars are seldom fought without hatred between nations.… Even where there is no national hatred and no animosity to start with, the fighting itself will stir up hostile feelings: violence committed on superior orders will stir up the desire for revenge and retaliation against the perpetrator rather than against the powers that ordered the action. That is only human (or animal, if you like) but it is a fact. Theorists are apt to look on fighting in the abstract as a trial of strength without emotion entering into it. This is one of a thousand errors which they quite consciously commit because they have no idea of the implications.
Although this statement was made in the context of interstate war, it can easily be applied to civil war, especially its protraction and increased violence. More generally, a theory has been offered that provides an emotional context for behavior at the onset of or during civil war. The theory is that of the ephemeral gain that proved to be robust in explaining the rise of extremism and consequent mass violence in a variety of settings (Midlarsky 2005; 2009; 2010; 2011a, b).
An Emotion-Based Theory
The ephemeral gain theory posits that anger and violent manifestations are more likely when, after an earlier period of subordination, an identifiable social group, often a nation-state, experiences a major societal gain (e.g., territory, population, authority), which is then followed by a critical loss, or the threat of its imminent occurrence. This theory incorporates Marxian or Davies J-curve like emphases on the future and dovetails with future-oriented game theoretic concerns (Garfinkel and Skaperdas 2000). But past events are crucial to ephemeral gain theory. The shadow of the past and the shadow of the future coincide in the bleak expectation that future political conditions easily could be just as oppressive as those of the past. The threat and fear of reversion to a subordinate condition can lead to the anger that fuels the mass murder of putative enemies, most of them innocents.
This theory has been applied to multiple forms of political extremism, including the rise of Italian, Hungarian, and Romanian fascism, Nazism, radical Islamism, and Soviet, Chinese, and Cambodian communism. Other applications include a rampaging military (Japan, Pakistan, Indonesia) and extreme nationalism in Serbia, Croatia, the Ottoman Empire, and Rwanda. Polish anti-Semitism after World War II and the rise of separatist violence in Sri Lanka are also examined (Midlarsky 2011b).
Instances of political extremism and conflicts of extraordinary length are rare, suggesting that the dynamics do not follow the cost-benefit calculations so common in other conflicts. Extremist behavior like suicide terrorism is a weapon of the weak in asymmetric conflict. Indeed, extremist groups such as the Nazis and Soviet communists arose in response to defeats that suggested insufficient force capability, which had to be countered by radical means, including mass murder.
Ephemeral gains occur within authority spaces. Authority space is understood as the portion of society over which governmental influence legitimately extends. Territorially-based authority spaces are frequently encountered, as in the distance from a central (capital) city that its authority extends. In itself, territorial contestation has been understood to be an important source of the onset and prolongation of interstate conflict (Toft 2003, 2009; Vasquez 2009; Walter 2003, 2006; Hensel 2012). A major purpose here is to explicate a plausible dynamic for lengthy intrastate territorial conflicts.
The Salience of Loss
Important here is the salience of loss, especially after more recent gains. Surprise at a sudden loss has an important consequence in the form of vividness (Loewenstein 1996). Both emotional pain and satisfaction can be multiplied substantially by the experience of surprise (Elster 2004, 160). Or, as George Loewenstein and Jennifer Lerner (2003, 624) suggest, “people respond with greater emotional intensity to outcomes that are surprising – that is, unexpected.”
It is necessary to understand the surprising nature of the loss, frequently because of the unrealistic expectations of insurgents. The emotions stemming from an automatic suppression of doubt and neglect of ambiguity, as well as the overweighting of small probabilities, lead to overconfidence in the face of daunting odds.
Finally, according to prospect theory, developed by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, losses are more highly valued than gains. Or put another way, the lost entity is psychologically more valued than an entirely identical entity that is gained (Kahneman and Tversky 1979, 2000). Experimental evidence has consistently demonstrated the asymmetry between losses and gains, even to the extent that, in contrast to gains, losses can generate extreme responses.
Anger
Protraction in and of itself suggests futility for the weaker protagonists, typically the insurgents. These lengthy conflicts persist through a succession of gains and losses, each of the later cycles in itself implying hopelessness for the insurgents. Yet the conflict persists despite the negligible probability of an outright insurgent victory. The sacrifice of human life, not to mention the daily hardships that continue in the face of overwhelming odds, needs to be explained. A consequence of the ephemeral gain, anger, has been importantly linked to risk acceptance. And it is this acceptance of the risk of failure that leads directly to a continuation of apparently hopeless (and at times hapless) insurgent activity.
Summarizing the remarkably consistent picture of anger that has emerged from a large number of studies, Paul Litvak et al. (2010, 290) conclude that “anger has been associated with a sense that the self (or someone the self cares about) has been offended or injured, with a sense of certainty or confidence about the angering event and what caused it, and with the belief that another person (as opposed to the situation or the self) was responsible for the event and with the notion that one can still influence the situation or cope with it” (e.g. Lazarus 1991; Ortnoy, Clore, and Collins 1988; Roseman 1984; Scherer 1999, 2001; Weiner, 1980, 1986).
Thus, loss generates anger at the injustice of the loss, especially when that loss occurred after a period of gain—the ascendancy that was preceded by subordination. The gain of that ethnic group has effectively been rendered null and void by the later loss. It is as if the gain had never occurred.
Justice as Fairness
Ever since the writings of John Rawls (1971, 1999, 2001), justice as fairness has been increasingly used as a basis for understanding the genesis of conflict or cooperation. At the same time, we may note the obverse. Lack of fairness can be perceived as an injustice. Hence, it is to our advantage to understand the conditions under which fairness evolves in dyadic relations.
When distinguishing among the consequences of violating the ethics of three fundamental realms, autonomy, community, and divinity, violations of the ethics of autonomy were more clearly associated with anger than were violations of the ethics of the remaining two. Between 74% and 85% of American and Japanese respondents reacted with anger to scenarios invoking the encouragement of a child to hit another, a drunken wife beater, and the theft of a purse from a blind person (Rozin et al. 1999, 578).
Justice inheres in the possession of personal rights; their violation stimulates anger and rebellion. Not only is the autonomy of a group violated, but if that violation occurs after an earlier period of ascendance that followed a still earlier subordination (in some cases following an even earlier triumphal period), then the anger can be augmented many times over. Especially if repeated over time in successive ephemeral gains, the strength of that anger can account for the repeated emergence of violent dissidence, even against overwhelming odds. This is especially true if there are successive ephemeral gains occurring over time, as in the case of the Kurds, one of the most protracted insurgencies of the 20th and 21st centuries (McDowall 2004; Yassin 1997).
Emotion, Anger, and Risk
There has been considerable research on the emotional sources of risky behavior. X. T. Wang (2006), for example, found that the emotional choice preference was more risk seeking than the rational choice preference in two experimental studies. Focusing now on the specifics of anger and risk, there are several major analyses of this relationship. They typically focus on the differential impacts of fear and anger. Whereas fear leads people to be risk-averse, anger has the opposite consequence; anger yields considerable risk acceptance (Lerner and Keltner 2000, 2001).
These findings mapped onto reactions to the events of 9/11, suggesting that the analysis here has implications not only for civil war protraction and increased violence, but for interstate war onset and national political stasis. Angry respondents expressed greater optimism about the future after 9/11; fearful respondents were more pessimistic (Lerner et al. 2003). After the difficulties of the Cold War, including an American defeat in Vietnam and Soviet initial ascendancy in space exploration, the implosion of the Soviet Union was a clear US victory. This American ascendancy was reinforced by the stellar triumph of US arms in the 1991 Gulf War versus Iraq. But this ascendant period prior to 9/11 proved to be ephemeral. Many Americans were angry; it appeared as if things would never be the same (Packer 2011).
Anger yields perceptions of certainty and control, thereby suggesting a more optimistic future. Fear has the opposite effect (Lerner and Keltner 2001; Lerner et al. 2003; Lerner and Tiedens 2006; Litvak et al. 2010). The optimism that stems from perceptions of control among angry people can lead them to take greater risks than more fearful individuals. Anger stemming from an ephemeral gain can yield risk taking that appears to defy rational conceptions of cost-benefit analysis. The 2003 invasion of Iraq and polarizing politics in the US, protracted virtually beyond endurance, appear to have been consequences in part of that anger.
—
Manus I. Midlarsky is Moses and Annuta Back Professor of International Peace and Conflict Resolution and Director, Center for the Study of Mass Violence, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, NJ.
References
Bester, Helmut and Kai A. Konrad. 2003. “Delays in Contests.” European Economic Review 48: 1169-1178.
Clausewitz, Carl von. On War, eds. and trans. Michael Howard and Peter Paret (Princeton NJ:
Princeton University Press, [1832] 1984) p. 138.
Elster, Jon. 2004. “Emotion and Action.” In Robert C. Solomon (ed.), Thinking About Feeling: Contemporary Philosophers on Emotions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 151-162.
Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Stergios Skaperdas. 2000. “Conflict Without Misperceptions or Incomplete Information: How the Future Matters.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44 (6): 793-807.
Hensel, Paul R. 2012. “Territory: Geography, Contentious Issues, and World Politics.” In John A. Vasquez (ed.), What Do We Know about War? 2nd ed. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield: 3-26.
Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky. 1979. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk.” Econometrica 47 (2): 263–92.
———. eds. 2000. Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Lazarus, Richard S. 1991. Emotion and Adaptation. New York: Oxford University Press.
Lerner, Jennifer S. and Dacher Keltner. 2000. “Beyond Valence: Toward a Model of Emotion-Specific Influences on Judgement and Choice.” Cognition and Emotion 14 (4): 473-493.
———. 2001. “Fear, Anger, and Risk.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 81 (1): 146-59.
Lerner, Jennifer S. and Larissa Z. Tiedens. 2006. “Portrait of the Angry Decision Maker: How Appraisal Tendencies Shape Anger’s Influence on Cognition.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 19: 115-37.
Lerner, Jennifer S., Roxana M. Gonzalez, Deborah A. Small and Baruch Fischoff. 2003. “Effects of Fear and Anger on Perceived Risks of Terrorism: A National Field Experiment.” Psychological Science 14 (2): 144-50.
Litvak, Paul M., Jennifer S. Lerner, Larissa Z. Tiedens, and Katherine Shonk. 2010. “Fuel in the Fire: How Anger Impacts Judgment and Decision-Making.” In Michael Potegal, Gerhard Stemmler, and Charles Spielberger (eds.), International Handbook of Anger: Constituent and Concomitant Biological, Psychological, and Social Processes. New York: Springer, 287-309.
Loewenstein, George. 1996. “Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65 (3): 272–292.
Loewenstein, George, and Jennifer S. Lerner. 2003. “The Role of Affect in Decision Making.” In Richard J. Davidson, Klause R. Scherer, and H. Hill Goldsmith (eds.), Handbook of Affective Sciences. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 619-42.
McDowall, David. 2004. A Modern History of the Kurds, 3rd ed. London: I. B. Tauris.
Midlarsky, Manus I. 2005. The Killing Trap: Genocide in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
———. 2009. “Territoriality and the Onset of Mass Violence: The Political Extremism of Joseph Stalin.” Journal of Genocide Research (special issue on Soviet mass violence), 11 (2-3): 265-83.
———. 2010. “Precursors of Terror: Origins of European Extremism.” In Rafael Reuveny and William R. Thompson (eds.), Coping with Terrorism: Origins, Escalation, Counterstrategies, and Responses. Albany: State University of New York Press, 25-52.
———. 2011a. “Extremism and Military Intervention in South Asia: Indian Muslims and Sri Lankan Tamils.” In Patrick James (ed.), Religion, Identity, and Global Governance: Ideas, Evidence, and Practice. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 128-58.
———. 2011b. Origins of Political Extremism: Mass Violence in the Twentieth Century and Beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ortnoy, Andrew, Gerald L. Clore, and Allan Collins. 1988. The Cognitive Structure of Emotions. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Packer, George. 2011. “Coming Apart: After 9/11 Transfixed America, the Country’s Problems were Left to Rot.” The New Yorker (September 12): 62-71.
Parkinson, Sarah E. 2013. “Organizing Rebellion: Rethinking High-Risk, Mobilization and Social Networks in War.” American Political Science Review 107 (3): 418-431.
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
———. 1999. The Law of Peoples; with “The Idea of Public Reason Revisited.” Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
———. 2001. Justice as Fairness: A Restatement. ed. Erin Kelly. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Roseman, Ira J. 1984. “Cognitive Determinants of Emotion: A Structural Theory.” Review of Personality and Social Psychology 5: 11-36.
Rozin, Paul, Laura Lowery, Sumio Imada, and Jonathan Haidt. 1999. “The CAD Triad Hypothesis: A Mapping between Three Moral Emotions (Contempt, Anger, Disgust) and Three Moral Codes (Community, Autonomy, Divinity).” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 76 (4): 574–86.
Scherer, Klaus R. 1999. “Appraisal Theory.” In Tim Dalgliesh and Mick J. Power (eds.), Handbook of Cognition and Emotion. Chichester, UK: Wiley, 637-63.
———. 2001. “Appraisal Considered as a Process of Multi-Level Sequential Checking.” In Klaus R. Scherer, Angela Schorr, and Tom Johnstone (eds.), Appraisal Processes in Emotion: Theory, Methods, Research. New York: Oxford University Press, 92-120.
Toft, Monica D. 2003. The Geography of Ethnic Violence: Identity, Interests, and the Indivisibility of Territory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2009. Securing the Peace: The Durable Settlement of Civil Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Vasquez, John A. 2009. The War Puzzle Revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Walter, Barbara F. 2003. “Explaining the Intractability of Territorial Conflict.” International Studies Review 5 (4): 137-53.
———. 2006. “Conclusion.” In Miles Kahler and Barbara F. Walter (eds.), Territoriality and Conflict in an Era of Globalization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 288-96.
Wang, X. T. 2006. “Emotions Within Reason: Resolving Conflicts in Risk Preference.” Cognitive Emotions 20 (8): 1132-52.
Weiner, Bernard. 1980. “A Cognitive (Attribution)-Emotion-Action Model of Motivated Behavior: An Analysis of Judgments of Help-Giving.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 39 (2): 186-200.
———. 1986. “Attribution, Emotion, and Action.” In Richard M. Sorrentino and E. Tory Higgins (eds.), Handbook of Motivation and Cognition: Foundations of Social Behavior. New York: Guilford Press, 281-312.
Yassin, Borhanedin. 1997. “A History of the Republic of Kurdistan.” The International Journal of Kurdish Studies 11 (1-2): 115-240.
Further Reading on E-International Relations
- What Determines The Implementation of Civil War Peace Agreements?
- Russian Military Aggression or ‘Civil War’ in Ukraine?
- How Qualitative Fieldwork Can Help Understand Civil Wars
- Fear as Driver of International Relations
- The Myanmar Conundrum: What Matters, and What Matters Less
- Self-Determination as a Process: The United Nations in South Sudan