Evidence of the important role which organised crime plays in civil war can be seen in conflicts ranging from Serbia to Sierra Leone. Despite this, there remains significant debate around the precise nature of the relationship between criminal activities and a range of conflict outcomes. This essay will set out the key causal mechanisms by which criminal activities can affect the duration, severity and resolution of civil conflict. It will then illustrate these mechanisms through one positive and one negative case study: the Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia (FARC) and Mexico’s Zapatista Army of National Liberation (EZLN) respectively. Following the logic of a Most-Similar Systems Design (Levy, 2008, p.10), these cases are suitable for comparison as they are both long-running, leftist, non-state armed groups (NSAGs) which hold territory and are situated in Latin America. However, they differ in their involvement in crime, allowing for a counterfactual comparison. The selection of the EZLN further fits with the “possibility principle” (Mahoney and Goertz, 2004), as they operate in a geographic area suitable for narcotics production but have avoided moving into crime. These cases can therefore illustrate the effects of two different approaches to illicit activities within the context of civil conflict, with the caveat that differences other than criminality may also contribute to divergent outcomes.
The Effects of Crime on Conflict Processes
Organised criminal networks have been identified by some scholars as a potential enabling factor in the outbreak of conflict. For example, Andreas (2004, pp.33–35) points to the role of the illegal arms trade in facilitating the outbreak of the Bosnian War, as well as the use of criminal networks as recruiting grounds for combatants. However, others have questioned any general relationship between the outbreak of civil conflict and criminality, with Cornell and Jonsson (2014, pp.3–4) arguing that the mere presence of criminal opportunities do not cause war. Instead, they focus on how criminal fundraising lengthen conflict by altering the incentive structures available to combatants. Even after the conflict has formally terminated violence can transform and continue as rebels become criminals in the post-conflict period (De Boer and Bosetti, 2015, pp.12–13; Collier, 1994).
This process of shifting incentives and motivations arising from engagement with illicit activities can also increase the severity of the conflict, particularly as it relates to predatory behaviour and the targeting of civilians (Kalyvas, 2015, pp.1530–1531; McMullin, 2009, p.84). Violence can also increase between and within criminalised groups, as they fight for control of criminal rents. Such a dynamic can be seen in the pre- and post-peace agreement behaviour of Colombia’s paramilitary AUC, which fragmented into a series of competing criminal bands as rival leaders fought for control of local narcotics profits (Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, p.11; Porch and Rasmussen, 2008, pp.530–531). Illicit activities therefore not only lengthen the conflict and create severe barriers to peace-building but may also increase violence against civilians and between rival groups.
Causal Mechanisms
While the dynamic between criminality and civil conflict is different in each case there are some key causal mechanisms which commonly link illicit activities to negative conflict outcomes. The first causal mechanism is the shift in incentive structures and motivations mentioned above. This process occurs at the societal, group and individual level. Kaldor (2012) argues that the use of crime to fund war reshapes a country’s economic system in such a way as to incentivise the continuation of the conflict. While the conflict is bad for the economy as a whole, the shared benefits to those groups directly involved in the “war economy” mean that they have incentives to prolong the conflict (Kaldor, 2012, pp.94–95). The same logic applies at the group level, where an organisation’s goals change as they become more invested in criminal profiteering, disincentivising serious attempts at peace (Steenkamp, 2017, p.11). At the individual level “professionals” and “mercenaries” (Kalyvas, 2015, p.12) with the skills and motivations to engage in crime enter the conflict, similarly contributing to the transformation of the conflict’s underlying dynamics (Dishman, 2005, pp.245–246; De Boer and Bosetti, 2015, p.10; Makarenko, 2004, p.138).
In addition to prolonging conflict, the participation of profit-focused individuals can increase civilian victimisation as discipline breaks down and exploitation takes precedence over the original political goals (Makarenko, 2004, p.137). This may take the form of ill-disciplined individuals engaging in predatory behaviour, or entire organisations changing their relationship towards the civilian population. This is exacerbated by the fact that as a group comes to rely on criminal funding it is less beholden to the local population for taxes and support (Von Einsiedel et al., 2017, p.5). The growing tendency of NSAGs to engage in crime has gone hand in hand with a move from hierarchical organisational structures towards decentralisation (Dishman, 2005). This can potentially deepen issues around discipline as ideological leaders have less oversight (Von Einsiedel et al., 2017, pp.4–5) and principal-agent problems come into play (Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, pp.11–12). Decentralisation and the development of isolated “fiefdoms” (Makarenko, 2004, p.139) also encourage fragmentation and in-fighting (Barnes, 2017, p.969), which could, in turn, lead to an increase in violence associated with “outbidding” (Pearlman and Cunningham, 2012, p.6; Kydd and Walter, 2006, p.76). Factionalised conflicts featuring decentralised actors will also present challenges for conflict termination as such groups are both more resistant to attack (Dishman, 2005, pp.248–249) and harder to engage in peace-building (Bosetti, De Boer and Cockayne, 2016, pp.4–5).
Another way in which organised crime can lengthen and worsen conflicts is by strengthening the NSAGs involved. In particular, involvement in transnational crime can strengthen groups by tying them into lucrative international networks. Cornell and Jonsson (2014, p.3) describe a “plow” effect, in which the high revenues from illicit trade drive groups to open new international trafficking routes. The development of such international alliances could bring a host of benefits to NSAGs, including greater income, arms supplies, training, foreign fighters and safe havens. This would make such a group both more durable and more mobile and therefore less likely to surrender. This fits with Bacon’s (2018) argument that terror groups which form international alliance networks are more durable and dangerous. Engagement in international criminal networks allows armed groups to develop such partnerships on both ideological and economic grounds.
These strengthening effects go further than the development of international networks. Firstly, any funding which can be drawn from crime will clearly allow a group to sustain their insurgency and develop their capabilities. Although the finances of clandestine organisations are difficult to ascertain such funding can be considerable, with one report putting Hezbollah’s income from crime at $1 billion a year (Meyer, 2017). Furthermore, widespread organised crime can weaken the state by lowering taxes, reducing legitimacy and corrupting institutions (De Boer and Bosetti, 2015, pp.12–14; Miraglia, Ochoa and Briscoe, 2012, p.13), which has the further effect of weakening the government relative to non-state adversaries. Any such equalising effect on the balance of power has the potential to lengthen and possibly widen the scope of the conflict (Buhaug, Gates and Lujala, 2009). Finally, involvement in organised crime can help non-state actors develop greater legitimacy among local populations, for example by protecting illegal crops (Felbab-Brown, 2017, pp.98–99; Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, pp.14–15) or redistributing illicit profits towards social services (Steenkamp, 2017, p.11). Increased legitimacy and the institutionalisation of rebel governance systems, whether funded by crime or not, are linked to increased conflict duration (Arjona, 2014; Balcells and Kalyvas, 2014).
The causal mechanisms described above frequently overlap. However, they can be summarised as falling into two main strands. Firstly, criminal activities change the incentive structures for various actors, thereby changing their behaviour in regard to both levels of violence and conflict termination. Secondly, illicit activities can affect the relative strength of state and non-state actors. Organisational decentralisation is linked to both of these strands, as it can define the incentives available to individuals as well as the strength and durability of organisations. In this sense, decentralisation can be seen as a mediating factor between criminality and conflict outcomes, as organisational structure partially determines the extent and effects of involvement in crime.
Simplified Summary of Causal Mechanisms
Causal Mechanisms | Conflict Processes | ||
Changed Incentives | Strength and Capabilities | Organisational Structure | Outcomes |
Investment in war economy | International alliances | Mediates other mechanisms | Longer conflict |
Predatory behaviour | Funding and equipment | Less oversight | Higher intensity |
Mercenary combatants | Weakened state | Greater durability | Civilian victimisation |
Fragmentation | Build legitimacy | Cause and effect of criminality | Post-conflict violence |
While these causal mechanisms provide a strong account of how involvement in crime can affect conflict processes, there are two important caveats. Firstly, illicit activities could potentially weaken a group rather than strengthen it, either through internal corruption (Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, pp.11–12) or by bringing the attention of foreign law enforcement agencies (Dishman, 2001, p.46). Being perceived as a criminal organisation could also cause a loss of legitimacy and lower support for a group (Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, p.11; Dishman, 2001, p.46). The effects of involvement in crime are not always unidirectional and could therefore have an opposite effect on conflict processes. Secondly, this account may suffer from issues of endogeneity. For example, it is unclear whether criminality causes decentralisation and ill-discipline, or whether decentralisation and ill-discipline cause involvement in crime. This issue goes to the heart of the crime-conflict nexus, as crime “is both a consequence of the war and, at the same time, a driver of the war” (Steenkamp, 2017, p.11). The mutually reinforcing nature of these causal relationships is not necessarily problematic, with scholars such as Makarenko (2004) building a picture of how crime and conflict feed off each other. However, it does indicate the necessity of carefully considering reverse causality when designing research on this issue.
Case Studies
Colombia and FARC
The conflict between the Colombian Government, its proxies and FARC has been described as the world´s “longest insurgency” (Leech, 2011). This highly fragmented conflict has long been intertwined with Colombia´s narco-trafficking industry, with profits from cocaine strengthening both FARC and its right-wing opponents (Otis, 2014, p.4; Holroyd, 2011, p.68). FARC began as a Marxist guerrilla group with support from foreign communist governments but increasingly relied on criminal fundraising as Cold War state-sponsorship dried up (Cook, 2011, p.21; Eccarius-Kelly, 2012, p.236) and as the fall of the Cali and Medellín cartels created a power vacuum in the booming cocaine industry (Holroyd, 2011, p.68). Despite having an impoverished, rural base of support FARC was able to engage in a widespread conflict against the government through its lucrative taxation of coca (Ortiz, 2011, p.137). This also strengthened their legitimacy among coca producing farmers, while their involvement in organised crime allowed them to build new networks for both the acquisition of weaponry and training (Ortiz, 2011, pp.137–139). Their ideological networks were supplemented by criminal ones, as it was able to pay groups as diverse as the Tijuana cartel, ETA, the Provisional IRA and the Libyan government for guns and training using narcotics (Berti, 2009; Ortiz, 2011, pp.139–140). FARC was clearly strengthened by its involvement in the cocaine trade, strongly suggesting that illicit fundraising lengthened the conflict and probably widened the theatre of war by improving the group’s capacities.
What is less clear, however, is the extent to which FARC’s involvement in the cocaine trade affected the incentives for either civilian victimisation or the continuation of the conflict. While some have described the FARC as a criminalised group (Makarenko, 2004, p.137) there is strong evidence to suggest that they maintained many of their political goals (Dishman, 2001, p.50; Eccarius-Kelly, 2012, pp.242–243), with their attacks consistently being directed against military targets (Saab and Taylor, 2009, p.460). FARC has targeted civilians, primarily through kidnapping for ransom (Eccarius-Kelly, 2012, p.240), however this has been a tactic since its inception and was more of a supplement to their repertoire of criminal activities than a consequence of them. Most tellingly, FARC attempted to embrace electoral politics with the formation of a quickly suppressed political party in the 1980s (Gomez-Suarez, 2007), and again following the most recent peace deal. The incentives arising from organised crime did not prevent the eventual termination of the conflict while the group has maintained its principal goal of political change, including through elections. This resistance to the transforming effects of criminality may lie in the organisational structure of the group, as FARC maintained some level of hierarchical ideological control (Saab and Taylor, 2009, pp.459–460; Eccarius-Kelly, 2012, pp.237–239) as well as in the fact that it has had more success in taxing than directly trafficking drugs (Saab and Taylor, 2009, pp.465–466). This can be contrasted with the rival AUC, which was more directly involved in narco-trafficking, attacked civilians more frequently and was more decentralised (Saab and Taylor, 2009, pp.461–463). Unlike FARC, the AUC devolved into a series of competing drug cartels following their peace deal with the government, conforming more to the expectations around changed incentives (Cornell and Jonsson, 2014, p.11; Porch and Rasmussen, 2008, pp.530–531).
Mexico’s EZLN
EZLN stands out against the backdrop of Mexico´s brutal drug war as they have avoided the violence and criminality associated with other actors in the country. While the Mexican Drug War has seen spiralling violence due to fragmentation (Kalyvas, 2015, p.1530; Phillips, 2015, p.326) and outbidding (Flanigan, 2012, p.289) EZLN has remained unified around its political goals, with subsequently low levels of violence following a quick ceasefire and long informal peace between it and the government (Ramsey, 2012). The fact that EZLN made a clear choice to avoid becoming embroiled in organized crime, despite favourable conditions to do so (Dishman, 2001, pp.42–47), creates a strong argument that non-involvement in crime has facilitated this lower intensity conflict. It is possible to reason counter-factually that if EZLN was involved in crime it would have seen a change of goals as the leadership became more reliant on criminal rents, as well as the recruitment of less disciplined combatants. It could also have expanded the conflict beyond the relatively limited geographical scope. This could have led to group to decentralize or fragment, potentially increasing the duration of conflict and level of violence.
There are several factors underlying the EZLN’s non-involvement in crime and the subsequent conflict trajectory. Firstly, while the EZLN’s political ideology emphasizes autonomous and democratic local decision-making, they did have a top-down ideological leadership which strongly and successfully mandated against both criminality and violence against civilians (Cuninghame and Corona, 1996, pp.17–18; Ramsey, 2012). Secondly, it was largely focused on land rights and local autonomy for indigenous groups (Cuninghame and Corona, 1996, pp.17–18; Godelmann, 2014). This narrower focus means that, unlike FARC, it did not have to sustain a nationwide campaign against the state and could instead survive on taxation. Furthermore, EZLN effectively utilised online networking methods which, combined with their credible claims to non-criminality, allowed them to develop into a grassroots political organisation by drawing donations from foreign NGOs (Dishman, 2001, p.47; Cuninghame and Corona, 1996, pp.13–14). While EZLN may have had the geopolitical opportunities to engage in organised crime, there was not the same necessity.
These cases illustrate the causal mechanisms which link involvement in criminal activities to longer conflicts and higher levels of violence. These mechanisms primarily relate to either changes to the incentives acting upon various groups or the strengthening of non-state groups relative to the state. This argument is sharpened by the fact that non-involvement in crime appears to have allowed EZLN to avoid these outcomes. However, there are clearly other factors which mediate the effects of involvement in crime. The organisational structure of a group can affect whether motivational transformation occurs or how criminality affects discipline and cohesion, while political aspirations can define the level of involvement in crime. It is also difficult to ascertain the direction of the causal relationship between crime and conflict outcomes, with various overlapping and mutually reinforcing relationships. Scholars should therefore be cautious in uniformly applying this understanding of the crime-conflict nexus across varied cases and conflicts.
References
Andreas, P., 2004. The Clandestine Political Economy of War and Peace in Bosnia. International Studies Quarterly, [online] 48(1), pp.29–52. Available at: https://academic.oup.com/isq/article-lookup/doi/10.1111/j.0020-8833.2004.00290.x [Accessed 4 Mar. 2019].
Arjona, A., 2014. Wartime Institutions: A Research Agenda. Journal of Conflict Resolution, [online] 58(8), pp.1360–1389. Available at: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/0022002714547904 [Accessed 11 Mar. 2019].
Bacon, T., 2018. Is the Enemy of My Enemy My Friend? Security Studies, [online] 27(3), pp.345–378. Available at: https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/09636412.2017.1416813 [Accessed 5 Dec. 2018].
Balcells, L. and Kalyvas, S.N., 2014. Does Warfare Matter? Severity, Duration, and Outcomes of Civil Wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution, [online] 58(8), pp.1390–1418. Available at: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/0022002714547903 [Accessed 11 Mar. 2019].
Barnes, N., 2017. Criminal Politics: An Integrated Approach to the Study of Organized Crime, Politics, and Violence. Perspectives on Politics, [online] 15(04), pp.967–987. Available at: https://www.cambridge.org/core/product/identifier/S1537592717002110/type/journal_article [Accessed 4 Mar. 2019].
Berti, B., 2009. Colombia’s FARC and the Basque ETA: Exploring the Tactical and Economic Partnership. Jamestown Foundation Terrorism Monitor. [online] 23 Jan. Available at: https://jamestown.org/program/colombias-farc-and-the-basque-eta-exploring-the-tactical-and-economic-partnership/ [Accessed 9 Mar. 2019].
De Boer, J. and Bosetti, L., 2015. The Crime-Conflict ‘Nexus’: State of the Evidence. Occasional Paper 5, United Nations University Centre for Policy Research. [online] Available at: http://collections.unu.edu/eserv/unu:3134/unu_cpr_crime_conflict_nexus.pdf [Accessed 7 Mar. 2019].
Bosetti, L., De Boer, J. and Cockayne, J., 2016. Crime-Proofing Conflict Prevention , Management , and Peacebuilding : A Review of Emerging Good Practice. [online] Available at: https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/ce1d/e0738fcaaaf4692de8bb2c0e97d5c957e3c6.pdf [Accessed 15 Oct. 2018].
Buhaug, H., Gates, S. and Lujala, P., 2009. Geography, Rebel Capability, and the Duration of Civil Conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, [online] 53, pp.544–569. Available at: http://jcr.sagepub.comhttp//jcr.sagepub.com [Accessed 14 Mar. 2019].
Cockayne, J., 2013. Chasing Shadows. The RUSI Journal, [online] 158(2), pp.10–24. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/03071847.2013.787729 [Accessed 5 Mar. 2019].
Collier, P., 1994. Demobilization and insecurity: A study in the economics of the transition from war to peace. Journal of International Development, [online] 6(3), pp.343–351. Available at: http://doi.wiley.com/10.1002/jid.3380060308 [Accessed 15 Oct. 2018].
Cook, T.R., 2011. The Financial Arm Of The FARC: A Threat Finance Perspective. Journal of Strategic Security, [online] 4(1), pp.19–36. Available at: http://scholarcommons.usf.edu/jsshttp://scholarcommons.usf.edu/jss/vol4/iss1/3 [Accessed 12 Mar. 2019].
Cornell, S. and Jonsson, M., 2014. The Nexus of Crime and Conflict. In: Conflict, Crime, and the State in Postcommunist Eurasia. [online] Philadelphia : University of Pennsylvania Press, pp.1–22. Available at: https://www-degruyter-com.ezproxy.lib.gla.ac.uk/downloadpdf/books/9780812208986/9780812208986.1/9780812208986.1.pdf [Accessed 5 Mar. 2019].
Cuninghame, P. and Corona, C.B., 1996. A Rainbow at Midnight : Zapatistas and Autonomy. Capital & Class, [online] 22(3), pp.12–22. Available at: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/030981689806600102 [Accessed 13 Mar. 2019].
Dishman, C., 2001. Terrorism, Crime, and Transformation. Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, [online] 24(1), pp.43–58. Available at: https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=uter20 [Accessed 11 Mar. 2019].
Dishman, C., 2005. The leaderless nexus: When crime and terror converge. Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/10576100590928124 [Accessed 8 Apr. 2018].
Eccarius-Kelly, V., 2012. Surreptitious Lifelines: A Structural Analysis of the FARC and the PKK. Terrorism and Political Violence, [online] 24(2), pp.235–258. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/09546553.2011.651182 [Accessed 24 Apr. 2018].
Von Einsiedel, S., Bosetti, W.L., Cockayne, J., Salih, C. and Wan, W., 2017. Civil War Trends and the Changing Nature of Armed Conflict. Occasional Paper. [online] Available at: https://i.unu.edu/media/cpr.unu.edu/attachment/1558/OC_01-MajorRecentTrendsinViolentConflict.pdf [Accessed 7 Mar. 2019].
Felbab-Brown, V., 2017. Organized crime, illicit economies, civil violence & international order: More complex than you think. Daedalus, [online] 146(4), pp.98–111. Available at: https://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/DAED_a_00462 [Accessed 11 Mar. 2019].
Flanigan, S.T., 2012. Terrorists next door? A comparison of Mexican drug cartels and middle eastern terrorist organizations. Terrorism and Political Violence, [online] 24(2), pp.279–294. Available at: https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ftpv20 [Accessed 13 Mar. 2019].
Godelmann, I.R., 2014. The Zapatista Movement: The Fight for Indigenous Rights in Mexico. Australian Institute of International Affairs. [online] 30 Jul. Available at: https://www.internationalaffairs.org.au/news-item/the-zapatista-movement-the-fight-for-indigenous-rights-in-mexico/ [Accessed 13 Mar. 2019].
Gomez-Suarez, A., 2007. Perpetrator blocs, genocidal mentalities and geographies: the destruction of the Union Patriotica in Colombia and its lessons for genocide studies. Journal of Genocide Research, [online] 9(4), pp.637–660. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/14623520701644440 [Accessed 21 Mar. 2019].
Holroyd, R., 2011. The Twilight of the Colombian Paramilitary. Past Imperfect, [online] 17. Available at: https://journals.library.ualberta.ca/pi/index.php/pi/article/view/18878/14666 [Accessed 7 Mar. 2019].
Kaldor, M., 2012. New & old wars : organized violence in a global era. 3rd ed. Cambridge: Polity.
Kalyvas, S.N., 2015. How Civil Wars Help Explain Organized Crime—and How They Do Not. Journal of Conflict Resolution, [online] 59(8), pp.1517–1540. Available at: http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/0022002715587101 [Accessed 4 Mar. 2019].
Kydd, A.H. and Walter, B.F., 2006. The Strategies of Terrorism. International Security, [online] 31(1), pp.49–80. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1162/isec.2006.31.1.49.
Leech, G.M., 2011. The FARC : the longest insurgency. London: Zed Books.
Levy, J.S., 2008. Case Studies: Types, Designs, and Logics of Inference. Conflict Management and Peace Science, [online] 25, pp.1–18. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1080/07388940701860318 [Accessed 30 Sep. 2018].
Mahoney, J. and Goertz, G., 2004. The Possibility Principle: Choosing Negative Cases in Comparative Research. The American Political Science Review, [online] 98(4), pp.653–669. Available at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4145330.
Makarenko, T., 2004. The Crime-Terror Continuum: Tracing the Interplay between Transnational Organised Crime and Terrorism. Global Crime [online] 6(1), pp.129–145. Available at: https://www.iracm.com/wp-content/uploads/2013/01/makarenko-global-crime-5399.pdf [Accessed 4 Mar. 2019].
McMullin, J., 2009. Organised Criminal Groups and Conflict: The Nature and Consequences of Interdependence. Civil Wars, [online] 11(1), pp.75–102. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/13698240802407066 [Accessed 7 Mar. 2019].
Meyer, J., 2017. The Secret Backstory of How Obama Let Hezbollah Off the Hook. Politico, Available at: https://www.politico.com/interactives/2017/obama-hezbollah-drug-trafficking-investigation/ [Accessed 28 Apr. 2018].
Miraglia, P., Ochoa, R. and Briscoe, I., 2012. Transnational organised crime and fragile states. Development Co-operation Working Papers, No. 5, OECD Publishing,. [online] Available at: https://doi.org/10.1787/5k49dfg88s40-en.. [Accessed 14 Mar. 2019].
Ortiz, R.D., 2002. Insurgent Strategies in the Post-Cold War: The Case of the Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia. Studies in Conflict & Terrorism, [online] 25(2). Available at: https://doi.org/10.1080/105761002753502484 [Accessed 12 Mar. 2019].
Otis, J., 2014. The FARC and Colombia’s Illegal Drug Trade. [online] Wilson Center Latin American Program. Available at: http://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/Otis_FARCDrugTrade2014.pdf [Accessed 11 Mar. 2019].
Pearlman, W. and Cunningham, K.G., 2012. Nonstate actors, fragmentation, and conflict processes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, [online] 56(1), pp.3–15. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1177%2F0022002711429669 [Accessed 8 Mar. 2019].
Phillips, B.J., 2015. How Does Leadership Decapitation Affect Violence? The Case of Drug Trafficking Organizations in Mexico. The Journal of Politics, [online] 77(2), pp.324–336. Available at: https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/680209 [Accessed 13 Mar. 2019].
Porch, D. and Rasmussen, M.J., 2008. Demobilization of Paramilitaries in Colombia: Transformation or Transition? Studies in Conflict & Terrorism, [online] 31(6), pp.520–540. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/10576100802064841 [Accessed 15 Nov. 2018].
Ramsey, G., 2012. How Mexico’s Guerrilla Army Stayed Clear of Organized Crime. InSight Crime. [online] 9 Jan. Available at: https://www.insightcrime.org/news/analysis/how-mexicos-guerrilla-army-stayed-clear-of-organized-crime/ [Accessed 13 Mar. 2019].
Saab, B.Y. and Taylor, A.W., 2009. Criminality and Armed Groups: A Comparative Study of FARC and Paramilitary Groups in Colombia. Studies in Conflict & Terrorism, [online] 32(6), pp.455–475. Available at: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/10576100902892570 [Accessed 9 Mar. 2019].
Steenkamp, C., 2017. The Crime-Conflict Nexus and the Civil War in Syria. Stability: International Journal of Security and Development, [online] 6(1). Available at: http://www.stabilityjournal.org/articles/10.5334/sta.522/ [Accessed 7 Mar. 2019].
Wulf, H., 2011. The Privatization of Violence: A Challenge to State-Building and the Monopoly on Force. The Brown Journal of World Affairs, [online] 18(1), pp.137–149. Available at: https://www.jstor.org/stable/24590784?read-now=1&seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents [Accessed 4 Mar. 2019].
Written by: Daniel Odin Shaw
Written at: University of Glasgow
Written for: Dr Adrian Florea and Dr Patrick Bayer
Date written: March 2019
Further Reading on E-International Relations
- Examining and Critiquing the Security–Development Nexus
- Should the Rome Statute Include the Crime of Ecocide?
- Mapping the Nexus Between Security and Development in the 21st Century
- The Development-Security Nexus: An Exploitative Past and Present
- The ‘Chilling Effect’: Are Journalistic Sources Afforded Legal Protection?
- “The Crime He Committed Was to Steal a Cow”: Moral Luck and Gacaca